A review of the
empirical literature about the relationship between fiscal decentralization and
economic growth
Revisión de la
literatura empírica acerca de la relación entre descentralización fiscal y
crecimiento económico
Sonia
Esteban-Laleona
Pablo de
Frutos-Madrazo
María Cristina
de Miguel-Bilbao*
Abstract
Traditionally,
academic debates about the benefits that the existence of multilevel government
structures provide have been directly related to the gains in efficiency that
derive from the processes of decentralization of the Public Sector. However, as
of the last decades, the Public Finance has broadened its analysis towards
other questions, one of them being whether the fiscal decentralization
influences positively in the economic growth of a country. The objective of
this document is to provide evidence on results of the main investigations out
of topic, examining, both the temporal and space horizons selected in these
studies, comparing the conceptual framework and the methodology used by the different
authors.
Keywords: fiscal decentralization, economic
growth.
Resumen
Tradicionalmente, los debates académicos sobre los beneficios
que la existencia de estructuras multinivel de gobierno proveen se han centrado
en los incrementos en eficiencia que se derivan de procesos de
descentralización del sector público. Sin embargo, en décadas recientes, el
financiamiento público ha llevado este análisis hacia otras cuestiones, una de
ellas es si la descentralización fiscal influencia de manera positiva el
crecimiento económico de un país. El objetivo de este documento es brindar
evidencia sobre los resultados de las principales investigaciones derivadas de
este tópico, examinar los horizontes tanto temporales como espaciales
seleccionados en estos estudios, comparando los marcos conceptuales y las
metodologías usadas por los diferentes autores.
Palabras
clave: descentralización
fiscal, crecimiento económico.
* Universidad de Valladolid, Campus Duques de Soria, España. Correos-e: sesteban@.uva.es, pablof@.uva.es, cdmiguel@efc.uva.es.
Introduction
The relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth is
a relatively new line of investigation. The traditional vision of the Theory of
Fiscal Federalism, only emphasizes the largest profits of efficiency that
derive from the processes of decentralization of the Public Sector.
Nevertheless, in the last decades a new line of investigation arises that tries
to discover if the processes of fiscal decentralization can, equally, promote
the economic growth of a country. More concretely, this new field of analysis
is inspired by the reflections made by Oates (1993). Oates argues that if from
a static perspective, the main benefits that derive from the installation of
multilevel government systems are expressed in terms of economic efficiency;
then from a dynamic perspective the potentialities of the fiscal
decentralization can be translated in terms of economic growth.
Nevertheless,
the existence of several government levels acting on the same territory
suggests immediately the question of the analysis of advantages and
inconveniences of fiscal decentralization, so much in the taking of decisions
about the public budgetary policies as in their incidence in citizens welfare
who cohabit in the different jurisdictions.
The theory of
the Fiscal Federalism under the outlined question has provided diverse
arguments about the functions, objectives and assignment of competitions among
the different coexistent government levels, mainly, in terms of efficiency and
redistribution of public spending and revenues (Oates, 1972). Restrictions on
fiscal instruments at the disposal of the different government levels add
realism to the analysis proposed and at the same time stand out the existence
of a tradde-off between efficiency and
redistribution. Tradde-off that is raised when there
are asymmetries in the information (Bird, 1993; Boadway,
1979, 2001) or discrepancies among the objectives wanted by subcentral
and central government levels (Oates, 1998).
Although this
article is not aimed to be an approach of the different doctrinal postures about the tradde-off between efficiency and redistribution, we
believe convenient to expose, succinctly, the advantages and inconveniences
of fiscal decentralization that are more
outstanding , in connection with the social welfare.
On one hand,
it should be pointed out that, when we try to quantify the profit of social
welfare that could be produced by fiscal decentralization we should consider so
much the grade of heterogeneity between the different territories as
differences of costs in the provision of public services (Oates, 1972; Boadway, 2001). In general, as we have already commented,
the subcentral governments, due to their biggest
proximity to those administered, possess a knowledge about preferences and cost
conditions that are not available to the central government, since the natural
tendency of this last one is the uniform provision although there are
differences among regions. Moreover, subcentral governments present a better bias and
capacity for internalizar the economic externalities
that take place in their territories (Porto, 2003).
Similarly, the
political component is positioned as one of the advantages of the
decentralization. A decentralized government in the field of public finance
contributes to the practice of democracy.[1]
This can be beneficial in countries that do not have a well-established
democratic tradition. The delegation of responsibilities from the central
government to regional governments will provide great benefits in terms of
increased efficiency of public spends, and therefore economic growth (Iimi, 2005). In addition, the decentralization can be
considered as a mechanism which allows to increase the participation of
population in the solution of more nearby problems, contributing in this way to
give priority to the management of public spends in terms of achieving greater
degrees of efficiency (Bodman and Ford, 2006).
On the other
hand, fiscal decentralization can improve regional development and technical progress (Oates, 1999). When an
environment of imperfect information and, furthermore, a great variety of
innovative measures are carried out to try to solve the same regional social
and economic problems, innovative jurisdictions generate information that can
very valuable for the rest. In turn, competition among fiscal communities can
make public officials from certain regions give services at the minimum
possible cost, increasing so the technical efficiency in their jurisdiction (Martínez and McNab, 2003). The
main inconvenience is that competition can lead some subcentral
governments undersupply public services and basic infrastructures, what will
impact negatively in regional economic growth (Break, 1967).
On the other
hand, a potential problem of fiscal decentralization is the fiscal competition
among different levels of government. In fact most of the doctrinal literature
about this topic see the competitive behavior between administrations like an
inefficiency cause more than like an improvement. However, there are authors
that think the competition plays an important paper in the contention of public
spending (Brennan and Buchanan, 1980; Oates, 2001). Also, the alternative to
the competition among different government levels is the coordination or
cooperation among jurisdictions. The benefits of social welfare provided by the
coordination are due to the fact that minimizes the political uncertainty and
it favors the negotiation and the resolution of interregional conflicts (King,
1988, 1995).
In short, the arguments set out before allow us to consider that fiscal
decentralization advantages are usually superior to inconveniences regarding
their relation with the social welfare.
The transcendency of this document resides in the fact of being
able to offer a reading guide that serves as a reference point to be
able to investigate how fiscal decentralization contributes to economic growth
and explains the mechanisms involved. In consequence, a rigorous analysis has
been made on the most outstanding empiric investigations about the impact that
the existence of multilevel government structures have on the economic growth
of a country. This document summarises the main
results that are derived from all these investigations, examining, both the
temporal and space horizons selected in these studies, comparing the conceptual
framework and the methodology used by the different authors, evaluating the
indicators used in the construction of the fiscal decentralization
variable and the specification of the growth dependent variable.
1. Conceptual
framework on the connection between fiscal decentralization and economic growth
Many of you
have discussed the costs and benefits that the establishment of multilevel
government structures provides. In fact, the developed focus up until recent
dates has been centered on analyzing how, from a static perspective,
decentralization can promote the economic efficiency of the system. The
possibility that subcentral governments can satisfy,
to a greater extent, the necessities of the individuals of their jurisdictions
have been the main argument fenced in favor of the decentralization of those
public goods and services whose benefits have clear space delimitations.
Equally, with the aim of reaching bigger bench marks of efficiency, the
existence of certain public services whose benefits expand along the whole
national territory advises that the central government should be responsible
for its supply.
It is also
necessary to remember that the main issue in the Theory of Fiscal Federalism is
not simply the dichotomy between centralization and decentralization. Each
government level has an important role to carry out. The challenge that should
be reached is to assign the responsibilities and the authority for government’s
functions to the appropriate levels. From this perspective, fiscal institutions
should be designed to be able to incorporate incentives so that the governing
class can select policies that promote the economic growth of their regions. In
this sense, the traditional vision of the Theory of Fiscal Federalism develops
new lines of investigation, amongst those we can outline if fiscal
decentralization promotes economic growth.
Concretely, in
the last decades, one of the most concerning matters, in different international
organizations is to determine if the economic activity of inferior units of
government can, to a certain point, foment the economic growth of a country. To
this respect, the plans to establish a connection between the phenomena of the
economic growth and the fiscal decentralization have been more an intuitive
question than a normative work (Esteban et al., 2006, 2008).
The idea that
underlies in this branch of the analysis of the Fiscal Federalism is that, if
from a static front, the fiscal decentralization of the Public Sector promotes
the economic efficiency, from a dynamic one it is able to promote economic
growth (Oates, 1993). The sub-central administrators know the necessities of
infrastructures of their territories better than the central government and,
therefore, they can satisfy them, in a greater measure. Equally, economic
literature offers another possible explanation on the phenomenon cause-effect
of economic growth and of fiscal decentralization: interpreting this last idea
as a superior good (Bahl and Linn, 1992). Only in
countries with relatively high per capita income levels decentralization ends
up being attractive, in the sense that its bene-fits
can be much more exploited that their disadvantages. Nevertheless, like Oates
(1999) exposes, the relationship among the income level per capita of a country
and the grade of decentralization of its Public Sector should not be
interpreted as a monolithic relationship. It is not true that the
decentralization is intensified without limits depending on level of income of
a country but rather an optimal level of fiscal decentralization has to exist
to be able to maximize the economic growth of a country.
From this
perspective, Martínez and Mcnab
(2003) tink about that the direct impact between
fiscal decentralization and economic growth may be uncertain. However, they
argue that potential indirect effects on both process can exist. It is,
decentralization may have an indirect impact on economic growth, through
consumer efficiency, producer efficiency, the geographical distribution on
resources, macroeconomic stability, corruption and captures by elites.
Specifically, Martínez and McNab
(2006a) make a model that establishes the potential indirect influence of
decentralization on growth through its impact on macroeconomic stability. More
recently, Feld et al. (2009) offer a broad
survey of this subject and they analyse the potential
impact of intergovernmental transfers on structural change as channel through
which may have an impact on aggregated economic performance. From a theoretical point of view, Schnellenbach et al. explain that “a status quo bias
implies political preferences in regions that are subjected to structural
changes typically tend towards preserving the declining incumbent industry”
(2009: 28). They investigate whether different fiscal institutions lead
policy-makers to take different responses to the declive
of well established industries. Schnellenbach et
al. (2009) results suggest that transfers in cooperative federalism are used for income policies rather than to
foster structural changes.[2]
In the light
discussions above, empirical evidence are, however, not in contradiction with
theoretical approaches.
2. Empiric evidence
on the connection between fiscal decentralization and economic growth
The intuition
that the processes of decentralization can potentialize
the economic growth of a country has originated, by the middle of the
nineteen-nineties, different works whose purpose was to contrast its empiric
validity. With the purpose of making easier the interpretation of the results
reached in different studies, we can establish the following classification. On
one hand, the investigations that center their interest in analyzing the
relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth from a point
of view establishing comparisons with other countries (cross-country studies).
On the other hand, studies that limit themselves to verify the impact that
multilevel government structures causes on the growth of a certain country
(single-country studies) (Anexxes i and ii).
In
cross-country studies, there are a range of studies that reflects in
quantitative terms the existent relationship between fiscal decentralization
and economic growth. The most outstanding contributions correspond to Oates
(1995), Phillips and Woller (1997), Davoodi and Zou (1998), Yilmaz (2000), Thieben (2000,
2003, 2005), Martínez and McNab
(2006a), Iimi (2005), Bodman
and Ford (2006), Thornton (2007) and Baskaran and Feld (2009).
The remaining
investigations center their interest in determining the connection of both
processes from a regional or national perspective (the single country
analysis).
1. The
behavior of the Chinese economy is analyzed in the studies of Zang and Zou (1998, 2001), Jin et
al. (2005), Lin and Liu (2000), Jin and Zou
(2005) and Qiao et al. (2008).
2. The
influence of the process of fiscal decentralization on the economic growth of
the United States is depicted in the investigations of Xie
et al. (1999), Akai and Sakata (2002) and Akai et al. (2007).
3. Behnisch et al. (2003) analyze the German
experience.
4. The
repercussion of fiscal federalism in the economic performance of the Swiss
Cantons is studied in Feld et al. (2004).
5. The
behavior of regions of India in connection with economic growth is interpreted
by Zhang and Zou (2001).
6. The
evidence of regional growth in Russia is studied in the investigation of Desai et
al. (2003).
7. Finally,
Carrion et al. (2006), Pérez and Cantarero (2006), Solé and Esteller (2006) and Esteban (2006) are among the most
recent studies, and they indicate the effect that fiscal decentralization has
caused on the economic growth of the Spain.
3. Chosen variables
The previous
spatial grouping is fundamental when examining the suitability of the variables
used by the different authors. The tables in the annexes number 1 and 2 picks
up the dependent and fiscal variables used.
3.1. Dependent
variable
Dependent
variable used in the majority of cross-country studies is the growth rate of
real Gross Domestic Product (gdp)
per capita, coming from International Financial Statistics of the international
Monetary Fund or of World Development Indicators of the World Bank (gdp).
Nevertheless, exceptions are Phillips and Woller
(1997), Martínez and McNab
(2006a) and Bodman and Ford (2006), who employ the
logarithm real of gdp
per capita (gdp’). Alternately, Thieben
(2000, 2003, 2005) uses different indicators to reflect the growth rate of the
economy of a country. This is, average growth rate of real gross fixed capital
formation –deflated by the producer price index– (gkap), total factor productivity
growth derived as a component of a macroeconomic production function (tfpg) and
average gross investment share of gdp (invgdp). On the other hand, Iimi
(2005) and Thornton (2007) use the average growth rate real of gdp per capita
for each country (gdp).
With the same
approach, in single-countries studies, the dependent variable used is the
growth rate of real province (state) income (Gypreg)
that comes from the Official Institutes of Statistic of the considered country.
Nevertheless, Behnisch et al. (2003) opt to
use the rate of total factor productivity growth (tfpg); Desai et al. (2003)
select industrial output of the it region deflated by the regional price
deflator. And lastly, in the Spanish case, Solé and Esteller (2006) elaborate two indicators that pick up
investments by all the levels of government divided by the previous year’s
capital stock. These indicators reflect two different types of spending categories:
roads ( I rit / Rit-1
) and education ( I eit
/ Eit-1 ).
3.2. Explanatory
variables
The measurement
of fiscal decentralization used by the mayority of
empirical studies as an explanatory variable is, at least, problematic. The
issue is that there is no single, fiscal decentralization is multidimensional.
Traditionally, researches are defined on the basic of a single dimension of
decentralization (share for subnational governments
in general expenditures or tax revenues). As Martínez
and McNab suggest, “There are many aspects of a
country’s fiscal affairs that ca be more or less
decentralized” (2003: 1608). That is, it can be the case that a country may be
more decentralized, because its subnational
government have more significant autonomous sources of revenues, or greater
freedom in how to make expenditures decisions on the services provided at the subnational level or the level of decentralization may be
small because regional officials are not democratically elected and are only
accountable to central government authorities (Bodman
and Ford, 2006). Also, it has been noticed that different methods of measuring
the degree of descentralization have produced
opposite correlation from empirical analysis of impact of decentralization on
economic growth. One reason for this discrepancy could be inconsistency of
measures (Halder, 2007). Fortunately, the empirical
literature ha evolved significantly in the precision
with which the explanatory variable for fiscal decentralization is measured.
For this reason, Halder (2007) has attempted to
construct the Composite Radio (cr). He considers the grant given by the central
authority to the sub-national authorities to be an important player “This is
because expenditure by the subnational levels of
government might be often financed by grants from the central government. In
such a case, the authorities of the lower of the government are not necessarily
reflected in the expenditure decisions. The grants are more likely to be tied
for specific projects” (Halder, 2007: 6). Equally,
the paper has brought in the average size of jurisdiction as a measure of
decentralization. Such a size is measured in two ways, in terms of area and
population. The smaller the size index, the more decentralized is the
government.
From the available
literature, we can state that different measures of fiscal decentralization
produce different outcomes when they are used in regressions for the same
dependent variable.
In cross-country studies, the database more widely used is The
Government Finance Statistics (gfs) of the International Monetary Fund (imf). Most
authors choose the budget data approach and they approximate the degree of
fiscal decentralization using the share of sub-national government
expenditures/revenues in general government expenditures/revenues; net of
intergovernmental transfers (fd-Exp
or fd-Rev).
Nevertheless,
in certain investigations, together with these indicators, other types of statiscal are included. This way, Oates (1995) uses an
alternative measurement for the independence of sub-national levels. This
author employs the self-reliance ratio (sr), as the share of own revenues
of lower levels in their total revenues.
Phillips and Woller (1997), on the other hand, build two additional
variables of fiscal decentralization. On one hand, the ratio of local
government expenditures to total government expenditures minus defense and
social security expenditures (fd-ExpNDEP). On the other one, they design
a variable (fd-Revgia)
by means of the transformation of the conventional indicator of tributary
decentralization (fd-Rev).
Concretely, fd-Revgia
is defined as the ratio of local revenues minus grants-in-aid to total
government revenues.
In turn, Thieben (2000) chooses different measures of fiscal
decentralization. On one hand, it uses the variables already used by other
authors (fd-Exp and sr).
On the other hand, it makes a simple transformation indicator of fd-Exp to test
for hump-shaped relationships between economic performance and fiscal
decentralization (fd-Exp2). Finally, he elaborates
an indicator (chsr)
to test whether increasing self-reliance of subnational
governments have effects on economic growth.
Additionally, Thieben (2003, 2005) uses in an alternative way, together
with the indicators of fiscal decentralization already employed in the year
2000, three dummy variables that are denoted fd-Exphigh for high degree of
fiscal decentralization, fd-Expmed
for medium degree of fiscal decentralization and fd-Explow for low degree of
fiscal decentralization. In turn, for Thieben
(2005) the model is augmented with a variable dummy (cd), which is assumed as 1 if the
governmental system is centralised and 0 if it is
federal.
Iimi
(2005) incorporates a measure of political freedom (pf) that reflects the degree of
political transfer to the municipal level. The reason is that political freedom
is closely linked with decentralization mechanisms and thus with economic
growth in the following sense. “Firstly, one might think that the benefits of
fiscal decentralization depend on how much political freedom a country enjoys.
If freedom is low, the benefits based on the Tiebout
mechanism may not be strongly realized. If freedom is high, the benefits may be
realized” (Iimi, 2005: 453). According to this
perspective, an interaction term fd*pf
should be of particular interest, since it allows us to test the hypothesis of
fiscal decentralization and political freedom as complementary.
Bodman and Ford’s (2006) analysis incorporates
traditional measures of fiscal decentralization (fd-Exp and
fd-Rev)
and a number of new measures that attempt to account for different degrees of
sub-national fiscal autonomy. The dimension of fiscal decentralization
considered in this study, and the most important dimensions, is to what extent
is fiscal decision-making decentralised? This paper
presents three measures of tax revenue (tax-only) decentralization: subnational own tax revenue (tdec1), sub-national own and shared tax (tdec2) and total subnational
tax revenue (tdec3), all
calculated as the share of general government tax revenue. On the other hand,
own taxes refer to those taxes for which the sub-national government can
determine the tax rate or tax bases or both (rdec1,
rdec2 and rdec3).
Bodman
and Ford’s (2006) study also provides two measures of expenditures decentralization.
These measures are based on total sub-national expenditure and lending, minus
loan repayments, as a percentage of consolidated general government
expenditures, without social security payment (edec1
and edec2). edec1 excludes transfers to other levels
of government, whereas edec2
includes transfers to other levels of government net of received transfers.
Futhermore,
Bodman and Ford’s (2006) paper uses hump-shaped
indicatores based on the traditional budget dates measures. The countries
were divided into five equal sized groups, denoting very low, low, medium, high
and very high decentralization (fd).
Finally, a
number of other measures of government decentralization, omitted from previous
studies of federal decentralization and growth, are considered in the Bodman
and Ford’s (2006) paper.
1. The
number of sub-national jurisdictions in the intermediates and lower tiers of
government is considered (nsgvt).
2. An
indicator was included to account for electoral decentralization (Elect).
Taking the value of 0 if there are no sub-national elections, 1 if either local
or intermediate tiers of government are elected, or 2 if both are subject to
elections.
3. The
indicator of constitutional structure is an index of federalism, one to
five-point scale (fu): a)
unitary and centralized; b) unitary but decentralized; c)
semi-federal; d) federal but centralized, and e) federal and
decentralized.
4. Resource
decentralization is considered using the ratio of sub-national government
employees to central government employees (Employ).
The
independent variables of decentralization of Thornton’s (2007) study are the
average tax revenue of sub-national governments stemming from the tax bases and
tax rates over which they have full discretion, Ownrev,
and a variable to test for the notion of hump-shaped relation between
fiscal decentralization and growth proposed in Thieben’s
(2003) study, which is a quadratic indicator of Ownrev,
(Ownrev)*(Ownrev).
And, Lastly, Baskaran and Feld
(2009) present two different decentralization measures. The first measure (Rev.dec.1) is similar to the one used by
Thornton (2007). It is constructed by summing all sub-federal tax revenues for
which sub-federal governments may determine either rates, bases or both, and
then dividing the sum by total government tax revenues. The second measure
(Rev.dec2) is constructed by
summing all tax revenue from shared taxes for which sub-federal governments may
codetermine the revenue distribution or other allocation details of the joint
taxation system, and then dividing the sum by total government tax revenues.
If we center
on single-countries studies, the indicators that are used mostly are the shares
of spending/revenues by each level of government in consolidated government
spending/revenues across all levels, both in absolute terms as in values per
capita, or their derivations (fd-Exp; fd-Rev). Nevertheless, in Akai and Sakata (2002),
apart from the conventional indicators of revenues (fd-Exp) and expenses (fd-Rev), they
also elaborate three additional statistical. On one hand, those that seek to
reflect the grade of fiscal autonomy of a sub-central government in a State (ai and
aii). On the other hand, a normalized
statistical one (pri)
which reflects both revenue and expenditure aspects of fiscal decentralization.
ai is defined as the ratio of local government’s
own revenue to total revenue, with revenues excluding federal grants; aii is
the ratio of local government’s own revenue to total revenue, with revenues
including federal grants; and pri represents a decentralization measure that
incorporates both revenue and expenditure shares. The production-revenue
indicator (pri)
is defined as the mean of fd-Exp and fd-Rev.
On the other hand, Lin and Liu (2000) and Desai et al. (2003)
apply an alternative focus of the measure of decentralization fiscal applied.
In the first study, the fiscal decentralization measure is the marginal
retention rate of locally collected budgetary revenue (mrr-Taxrev). In this study, the
fiscal decentralization measure is determined by how many the revenue
increments were kept by provincial governments. Whereas Desai et al.
(2003) use as a measure of fiscal incentives, the tax revenue retention rate
(rr-Taxrev).
This variable reflects only official taxes, collected and accounted for in
regulating government budgets.
In an
alternative way, Feld et al. (2004) depict the
grade of fiscal decentralization by means of the application of six alternative
statisticals. These authors use the habitual
indicators of revenues and expenses used in the literature (fd-Exp and
fd-Rev)
and four more that capture concrete aspects of the Swiss model of
decentralization. The first statistical (Mat-Grants) reflects the matching
grants per capita received in each Swiss Canton. This variable reflects the
financial importance that the matching grants have in the model of cooperative
federalism in Switzerland. The second indicator (Fisc-Comp)
indicates that the higher the difference of average tax burden of the
neighboring cantons, the higher the pressure of tax competition on the cantonal
and local tax authorities. On the other hand, the variable fragmentation (Fragm) is constructed by the number Communes in a Canton
divided by population. It is supposed to capture the lack of exploiting
economic of scale. Lastly, Urbanization (Urban), measured by the share of
people living in urban areas, is included to represent the new field of
economic geography that reflects that urban economic centres
develop more strongly that the periphery.
Qiao et
al. (2008)’s studie define two measures. The
first measure is similar to the one used in most studies; decentralization is
defined as the share of provincial fiscal expenditure in total fiscal
expenditure in per capita terms (fd-Exp per cap). The second measure is the index
equity in the regional distribution of fiscal resources (Equity). This measure
is defined as the ratio of the share of fiscal resources to the share of
population of a province as the province’s relative share of fiscal resources.
On the other hand, Solé and Esteller (2006) opt, for the Spanish case, for the
definition of two variable Dummies. These indicators reflect the moment when
decentralization took place in the responsibilities of road and education in
each one of the Spanish regions. dcrit
is a dummy equal to 1 if the regional government has the responsibility of
providing regional roads. Alternatively, deceit is weighted
sum of a dummy equal to 1 if the regional government has the responsibility of
providing primary and secondary education, and a dummy equal to 1 if the
regional government has the responsibility of providing higher education, with
the weights being the average share of both education levels in total education
investment.
Finally,
Esteban (2006) uses as a variable of fiscal decentralization the percentage of
public expense attributed to Spanish Autonomous Communities with respect to the
total of government expenditure in these Communities (Descgto).
4. Conceptual
framework employed
The theoretical
model mostly backed by economists has been that of Davoodi
and Zou (1998). The theoretical framework on which
these authors base theirs studies is the endogenous
growth model of Barro (1990), where the production
function has multiple inputs including private and public spending. This perspective
is adopted by Davoodi and Zou
(1998), Zhang and Zou (1998, 2001), [3] Xie et
al. (1999), Akai and Sakata (2002), Akai et al. (2007),[4] Iimi (2005), Jin and
Zou (2005), Carrión et
al. (2006), Pérez and Cantarero
(2006), Esteban (2006) and Baskaran and Feld (2009). Concretely, in the model of Davoodi and Zou (1998), the
public spending is divided in three government levels and the spending shares
are determined assigned at the different government levels with the
macroeconomic objective of maximization of the growth. The essential
implication of the models is that for a given share of total government
spending to gdp,
the growth-maximizing government budget shares are proportional to the relative
productivity of federal and local level governments.[5]
On the other
hand, the studies of Lin and Liu (2000), Martínez and
Mcnab (2006a), Thieben
(2003, 2005); Feld et al. (2004) and Bodman and Ford (2006) use a different approach. Following Mankiw et al. (1992), these authors use the model of
exogenous growth of Solow (1956) and they introduce the fiscal decentralization
as a variable explanatory of the growth rate of output per capita. The
cornerstone of these last works is to admit that
the exogenous parameter not only reflects technological aspects of the economy
but also a measure of the economic performance of the decentralized Public
Sector. I.e. the level of technology reflects not just technology but
also differences in resource endowment and institutions across
countries/regions and over time, as well as in other non-bservable
countries/region-specific characteristics. This disintegration of the term technological
progress is consistent with the economic literature about the growth and
with the hypotheses of conditional convergence (Barro,
1990; Sala, 1994).
In any case,
the previous studies probably use a theoretical framework ad-hoc, since they
don’t allow to identify the causes of the estimated effect of decentralization
in the economic growth of a country. In this sense, the procedure used by Sollé and Esteller (2006) is
quite different to that employed in previous investigations. This authors
consider the assignment process among alternative investments and, then, they
compare it with the effect that this assignment process causes in decentralized
decision-taking scenario as in another centralized. In this point of the
analysis, if the assignment process differs among the two contexts of
decision-taking, they are able to identify the inefficiency taken place under
the centralized government structure. Also, combining the obtained results with
the estimates of the effects of the outlined alternative investments (roads and
education) on the economic growth, they can determine the gain from the output
due to the better assignment in the investments in the decentralized
decision-taking scenario.
Among the two
most backed theoretical focuses, models of endogenous court versus
models of exogenous court, it seems that there is a clear preference to
contrast the influence of the processes of fiscal decentralization empirically
on the economic growth from an environment of endogenous growth (Annexes i y ii). Concretely, the fact stands out
that most of the studies of individual countries are based theoretically on the
contributions of Barro (1990), where the government
expenditure assigned at each government level is added to the production
function as one more productive input.
5. Empiric
methodology
The econometric specifications that are used, mainly refer to two
particular procedures in the treatment of the data: regressions with
cross-section data as opposed to those that are solved on a panel of data
(Annexes i
y ii).
In the panels
of data the variables of annual frequency are usually used. Although, it is
true that, it is possible to establish panels with data averages of more than a
year of frequency, with the purpose of grasping the possibility of long term
effects. This is the case detected in Davoodi and Zou (1998) and Phillips and Woller
(1997) who use a panel on average data covering five years or decenal frequency, in the first case; and of annual
frequency, triennial and five-year, in the second case.
The pros and cons of these two types of data treatment are discussed in
the investigations of Thieben (2000, 2003). This
author grants, in both studies, a bigger priority to the regressions of
cross-section with data annual averages. However, in spite of most authors lean
for the methodology applied on panel data, Akai and Sakata (2002) use
regressions with cross-section data and they introduce a variable dummy that
picks up the specific characteristics of each country.
Equally, one
empirical issue that should be considered before analysing
the relation between decentralization fiscal and economic growth concernid the potencial endogeneity of fiscal decentralization to the growth
process. A significant body of empirical literature suggest that the level of
income is a determinant of decentralization fiscal (Oates, 1972; Panizza, 1999; Eller, 2004). As it is suggested in Bodman and Ford (2006)’s report, development stimulates
demand for variety and quality in the range of public services being provided
whilst increasing the revenue raising capacity of governments, making
decentralization affordable. “If federal decentralization has a high income
elasticity, then higher income per capita may allow the constitution of a new
level of decentralization. If fiscal decentralization affects economic growth,
then the new level of decentralization will in turn have an impact on the of
income. Thus suggest a potential bidirectional relationship between fiscal
decentralization and economic growth” (Bodmand and
Ford, 2006: 13). Moreover, Breuss and Eller (2004)
and Iimi (2005) acknowledge that unobservable and
omitted variables that tend to simultaneously may also exit. If is this the
case, then simply including fiscal decentralization in a growth regression
could lead to simultaneity bias.
The different
channel of interference and potencial bi-directional
causalities between fiscal decentralization and economic growth have not been
sufficiently considered within theoretical models or empirical specifications,
respectively. Breuss and Eller (2004) suggest that
given potential bi-directional causalites it is also
necessary to address the research regarding the impact of economic growth on
fiscal decentralization and examine the various channels of interference. “It
is important to specify the determinants and dimension of both fiscal
decentralization and economic growth and clarify wich
exogenous variables determine simultaneously the two variables of inters (e.g.
population growth)” (Breuss and Eller, 2004: 8). If
fiscal decentralization and economic growth are endogenously related then
failure to control for this econometric issue would result in inconsistent parametres estimate. And additional problem in testing and
controlling for endogeneity is the lack of control
variables that are correlated with decentralization, uncorrelated with growth,
and available across countries and time. The literature of data has focused
primarily on the contemporaneous relationship between decentralization and growth; ignoring for the most part the
potential for time-wise causality (Martínez and Mcnab, 2003: 610).
From this
point of view, the results of some researches assume that there is one way
causality between fiscal decentralization and economic growth; whereas
others authors consider that there are
some problems in Ordinary Least Square (ols) estimations, and provide
corrected estimations of results. In order to provide correct estimates, most
of the studies value the effect of fiscal decentralization by considering endogeneity. They correct these potential problems, using
Three Stage Least Squares (tsls)
and adding the Instrumental Variables (iv)
to the exogenous ones already included in the basic regression model.
Regarding the
estimator used by different authors, the estimador of
ols is
the one that prevails in most of studies. Nevertheless, Zhang and Zou (1998), Yilmaz (2000) and Thieben (2000) use the estimator of General Least Square (gls); Akai et
al. (2007) opt for Maximum Likelihood (ml)
estimation; Desai et al. (2003) use the Three Stage Least Squares (3sls) estimate to minimize the
simultaneity and endogenousity of some explanatory
variables that can be the case of the transfers received by the subcentral governments.
More
specifically, and among the most recent investigations, Bodman
and Ford (2006) go even further in Thieben’s (2000,
2001) analysis of the relationship between fiscal decentralization and the
components of the growth equation. His study uses pooled cross-section
regression. On the other hand, in Thieben (2005) the
simple ols
method is used with the assumption that the independent variables are
exogenous. The estimate is a pure cross-section analysis; that is, short-term
time effects were eliminated by forming averages to enable only the long-term
effects to be measured. Equally, in Thornton (2007), given the relatively small
sample size, the estimation technique was ols with average data for the
period. Whereas the use of ols
in this context implies that the explanatory variable is exogenous, which may
be problematic, the relatively small sample prevents the use of an alternative
Instrumental Variable (iv) method.
In the same way, in Iimi (2005) and Esteban (2006)
the estimation results are based on the ols and iv technique using data averages for the period of
reference.
Jin and Zou (2005) use a panel data set for 30
provinces in China. The regression analysis in this study uses the panel data
sets combining time series and cross section. All coefficients are estimated
with fixed-effects with corrections for panel heteroskedasticity
and and panel serial correlation.
Of particular
note, comparing the ols
and iv results, the iv models tend to estimate
systematically smaller effects of fiscal decentralization than the ols
regressions, implying that the ols results are biased.
6. Discussion about
the results from the literature review
In theory, it
is expected that the decentralization lead to efficient provision of local public
services and a rapid economic growth but the empirical evidence has shown that
there is not a direct relation cause-effect between fiscal decentralization and
economic growth is ambiguous.
The results of
the studies on the impact of fiscal decentralization on economic growth that
have been conducted on a cross-country analysis, indeed end up with
controversial results (Annex i).
Iimi
(2005) finds that fiscal decentralization has a significant positive impact on
per capita growth, implying that the transfer of fiscal functions to
sub-national governments is condicive to economic
growth.
Thieben’s
(2005) studies can conclude that decentralization does generally have a
positive influence on growth. The results show that fiscal decentralization can
promote growth to limited extents. Countries with medium decentralization have
a slightly higher investment ratio and slightly higher growth in total factor
productivity than countries with a high or a low degree of decentralization.
Similarly, Bodman and Ford (2006) suggest that whilst little evidence
of a direct relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth is
found, some evidence is found to support the hypothesis that a medium degree of
fiscal decentralization is positively related to growth in the capital stock
and level of human capital.
At the same time, the empirical results presented in Thornton (2007)
suggest that when measures of fiscal decentralization are limited to the
revenue over which sub-national governments have real autonomy, there is no
statistically significant relationship between fiscal decentralization and
economic growth. Whereas, when revenue decentralization is measured by only
those own-revenue, over which sub-national government have full discretion,
fiscal decentralization does not appear to affect economic growth of mid ot high income countries. He indicates that “A serious
problem with much of the literature on the macroeconomic impact of fiscal
decentralization is that it fails to make an appropriate distintion
betwen admi-nistrative and
substantive decentralization by not recognizing that high sub-national revenue
and spending shares do not necessarily indicate high local autonomy” (Thornton,
2007: 65). Baskaran and Feld
(2009) find that there is no evidence that revenue decentralization leads to
lower growth rates. “On the contrary, there is even some evidence that
sub-federal control over shared taxes is beneficial for economic outcomes. On
the other hand, federations seem to have lower growth rates” (Baskaran and Feld, 2009: 17).
On the other
hand, the empirical results concerning the impact of decentralization on
economic growth for individual countries are not less ambiguous than those
detected in the studies among countries (Annex ii).
As Jin y Zou (2005) suggest, the effects of fiscal
decentralization on any given case depend critically on the nature of fiscal
institutions and the type political system. These authors suggest that
expenditure and revenue decentralization levels should further diverge to benefit
provincial growth. In the first phase (1979-1993), provincial economic growth
is negatively associated with expenditure decentralization and positively
associated with revenue decentralization. The negative association between
expenditure decentralization and provincial real gdp growth rate is consistent
with Zhang and Zou’s (1998) results. Hence, their
interpretation, that the central government may be in a better position to
undertake public investment with nation-wide externalities in the early stages of
economic development, is supported by this result. In the second phase
(1994-1999), the regression results testing the relationship between fiscal decentralization and growth for the period after
1994, when the tax assignment system was applied, suggest that there is
no significant association between expenditure decentralization and provincial
economic growth. Meanwhile revenue decentralization is found to be negatively
associated with provincial economic growth, with a high level of statistical
significance.
On the other
hand, in the case of the Indian economy, Zhang and Zou
(2001) find a positive and significant relationship between the per capita
fiscal decentralization shares and state economic growth in India; While in the
case of the Chinese economy the results of Zhang and Zou
(1998) reproduce themselves.
Jin et al.
(2005), however, find a weakly significant positive effect of expenditure
decentralization on the economic growth of the same sample of Chinese provinces
over time. The most important difference between these is that Zhang y Zou (1998) do not use time dummies.[6]
Lin and Liu (2000) corroborate the result of a positive impact of
decentralization on economic growth in Chinese provinces for the period 1970 to
1993.
Opposed to
Zhang and Zou (1998)’s theories, Qiao
et al (2008) indicate that fiscal decentralization significantly
affected economic growth. These findings may be explained not only by the
differences in the specifications of economic models usual in the two studies,
but by the difference in the time periods covered by the two data sets. Fiscal
decentralization significantly affected economic growth but at the cost of less
geographical equity. Morever the relationship between
the level of decentralization and economic growth is non-linear.
Desai et
al. (2003) find that an increase in the retention tax (as a share of
locally generated taxes that are left with the regional budget), for most
Russian regions is generally accompanied by stronger economic growth.
From another perspective, Feld et al.
(2004) indicate that matching grants have a negative impact on economic
performance while tax competition is at least not harmful to economic
performance. Tax competition appears to induce Swiss Cantons to allocate public
funds more efficiently so that economic performance of a canton could improve.
Exploring the American economy, Xie et al.
(1999) also find for the US states insignificant coefficients on local and
state spending shares, but they argue that these insignificant fiscal
decentralization shares indicate consistency with growth maximization. Akai and
Sakata (2002) demonstrate that the expenditure decentralization positively
affects economic growth of the US states. However, decentralization on the
revenue side and the indicators for fiscal autonomy of sub-national levels do
not have a significant impact. Equally, Akai et al. (2007) underline the
positive influence on economic growth. These authors test the hypothesis of a hump-shaped
relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth and find that
US states with a low degree of fiscal decentralization tend to grow stronger.
Examining the
impact on growth from the perspective of centralization, Behnisch
et al. (2003) report a statistically significant positive effect of
overall centralization on the German productivity growth.
As for as
Spanish economy is concerned, Carrion et al. (2006), Pérez
and Cantarero (2006) and Esteban (2006) emphasize on
the fact that the contribution that the Spanish fiscal decentralization process
has had positive effects on regional economic growth.
Equally, the
analysis of the Spanish economy done by Solé and Esteller (2006) confirm the hypothesis of the Decentralization
Theorem concerning the greater responsiveness of sub-central government to
local needs. Their results show the need of decentralizing investment in order
to maximize the rate of economic growth. This way, roads and educational investiments made by sub-central governments in Spain is
much more sensitive to changes in output than the investiment
made by central government. As Solé and Esteller (2006) suggest, if sub-central governments are
more responsive to needs than the central government, the composition of the
capital stock under centralization is not efficient. Therefore, the Spanish
fiscal decentralization process would have eliminated this distortion.
Overall, there is a large empirical literature on the relationship
between fiscal decentralization and economic growth. However, some results
indicate that this connection is inconclusive. To make good this relation, Feld et al. (2009) offer a survey of these empirical
studies, and also use a quantitative meta-analysis to explore the true size of
effects and to evaluate its significance. “In the context of decentralization
and economic growth, the idea is to pool the estimates from several studies and
to calculate an average effects” (Feld et al.
2009: 33). That is, they explore whether the choice of a particular measure of
decentralization, a particular specification modifies the estimated effects.
They report a tendency in the studies that there is a mild positive effect of
fiscal decentralization, when is properly measured as a type of competitive
government. As they conclude, the meta regressions shed more light on which
study characteristics tend towards support for a positive impact of fiscal
decentralization on economic growth. Mainly, “this relationship is expected in
developed countries lending support to the suspicion that fiscal
decentralization is having much different effects in less developed than in
developed countries. In addition, single country studies tend to indicate a
positive effects of federalism on economic growth which may be the results of
their possibility to consider the specific differences a country more strongly”
(Feld et al., 2009: 48).
Conclusions
In theory, it
is expected that decentralization will lead to efficient provision of local
public services and will result in a rapid economic development. However, the
studies presented here suggest that the relationship between fiscal
decentralization and economic growth is ambiguous.
More
concretely, in cross-country analysis the main conclusion that can be extracted
is that a hump-shaped relationship seems to exist between the processes of
fiscal decentralization and economic growth. Also, due to the specific problem
in developing countries, it is necessary to limit the empirical analysis only
to high income-countries. In high income-countries, the results suggest that
the gains in growth that can be achieved through decentralization are limited.
Successive increase of a relatively low degree of fiscal decentralization does
stimulate investment and as a result, it promotes economic growth. But there seem to be a point beyond which,
further decentralization no longer results in progress. The economic
explanation that emerges from these results is that if the grade of fiscal
decentralization is too high, intervention by central government that would
promote growth is not performed, and public goods with clear spatial
delimitations of its benefits will not have spillover effects with their repercutions. In the same way, too low a degree of
decentralization can lead to loss of economic growth because the local
government offices would not have sufficient incentives to produces public
goods as efficiently as possible, as a consequence of such knowledge not
sufficiently taken into account.
While in studies within a single country, the effects of fiscal
decentralization on any given case depend critically on the nature of the
fiscal institution and political system in place. Nevertheless, the results
seem to lean towards the hypothesis that a medium degree of fiscal decentralization tends
to best promote economic growth. In other words, an optimal grade of
decentralization would be able to capitalize a country’s economy at a larger
pace than it would be at inferior levels or superiors of fiscal
decentralization.
As a final conclusion, cross-country studies as well as single-country
analysis, tend to be inconclusive and they offer ambiguous and differents results. Among the factors that can cause these
ambiguous and differents results, the ones that stand
out most are, the different methodological approaches, the analytical unit
applied (studies among countries vs. studies single country) and the diverse
designs of the variable fiscal decentralization. In this sense, future research
may consider developing more disintegrated measures of fiscal decentralization.
The degree of decentralization should not be measured by the share of
expenditure/revenue of lower level with respect to total expenditure/revenue of
the government. In turn, it seems necessary to measure the differences in
current autonomy among jurisdictions. It is necessary to elaborate measures of fiscal
decentralization that represent changes in fiscal decentralization or
grasp qualitative restrictions of sub-national autonomy. In equal manner, it
would be advisable that those publicly responsable
for each country’s Official Institute of Statistics draw up better and wider
ranged time series data. Finally, it is
important to note that new investigations, based on theoretical models that are
able to verify the relationship that lies between fiscal decentralization and
economic growth, are very necessary. For example, it is required further
research to come up with a clearer identification of the transmission channels
by which fiscal decentralization should promote economic growth.
Annex i
Empirical
studies on the influence of fiscal decentralization on economic growth in
cross-country studies
Author |
Space field |
Time field |
Dependent variable |
Variable of fd |
Analytical framework |
Empiric methodology |
Main results |
Oates (1995) |
40 countries |
1974-1989 |
gdp |
fd-Exp, sr |
Not explicit any theoretical model |
No details available |
Positive and significant correlation between
fiscal decentralization and economic growth |
Phillips and Woller (1997) |
23 countries ldc |
1974-1991 |
gdp |
fd-Exp, fd-ExpNDEF, fd-Rev, fd-RevGIA |
Levine and Renett (1992) and Sala-i- Martin (1997) |
Panel data. Fixed Effects Model. ols |
Fiscal decentralization no robust effect on
economic growth |
Davoodi and Zou (1998) |
46 developing and developed countries |
1970-1989 |
gdp |
fd-Exp |
Model of endogenous growth of Barro (1990) |
Panel data. Fixed Effects Model. ols |
Decentralization of spending reduces economic
growth, but this relation is not significantly |
Yilmaz (2000) |
46 countries |
1971-1990 |
gdp |
fd-Exp |
Not explicit any theoretical model |
Panel data. Fixed Effects Model. gls |
Decentralization is not significant to
economic growth |
Thieben (2000) |
26 developed and developing countries |
1975-1995 |
gdo, gkap, tfpg |
fd-Exp, fd-Exp2, sr, chsr |
Model of endogenous growth without providing
more particulars |
gls |
The capital formation
is positively related to the increments of the sub-central governments’ self-reliance |
Thieben (2003) |
21 developed countries |
1973-1998 |
gdo, invgdp, tfpg |
fd-Exp, fd-Exp2, fd-ExpLOW, fd-ExpMED,
fd-ExpHIGH,
fd-Rev,
sr |
Model of economic growth of Solow enlarged by Mankiw et al. (1992) |
gls |
Convergence of the countries of high-income
of de oecd toward a medium degree of
decentralization of expenditures can promote the economic growth |
Martínez and McNab (2006a) |
52 developed and developing countries. |
1972-1997 |
gdp |
|
Model of economic growth of Solow enlarged by Mankiw et al. (1992) |
Panel data. Fixed Effects Model. gls |
Fiscal decentralization is positively related
to macroeconomic stability |
Thieben (2005) |
21 High-income oecd countries |
1973-1998 |
gdp, invgdp, tfpg |
fd-ExpLOW, fd-EexpMED, fd-ExpHIGTH
and cd |
Model of economic growth of Solow enlarged by Mankiw et al. (1992) |
ols |
The hypothesis that fiscal decentralization
can promote growth has a limited extent |
Iimi (2005) |
51 countries |
1997-2001 |
gdp |
fd, pf and fd*pf |
Endogenous growth model provided by Davoodi
and Zou |
ols and iv |
Fiscal decentralization has a significant
positive impact on growth |
Bodman and Ford (2006) |
21 oecd countries |
1981-1998 |
gdp |
fd-Exp, fd-Rev, tdec, rdec, edec, fd, nsgut, Elect, fu, Employ |
Model of economic growth of Solow (1956) |
ols |
Medium degree of decentralization is best for
the growth in both physical and human capital |
Thornton (2007) |
19 oecd countries |
1980-2000 |
gdp |
Ownrev, Ownrev*Ownrev |
Not explicit any theoretical model |
ols |
No robust effect of revenue decentralization
to economic growth |
Baskaran and Feld (2009) |
23 oecd countries |
1975-2001 |
gdp |
Rev.dec.1; Rev.dec.2 |
Endogenous growth model provided by Davoodi
and Zou |
Panel data; ols; random effects, fixed
effects estimations |
Fiscal decentralization and economic growth
are unrelated but there is some evidence that sub-national control over
shared taxes is beneficial for growth |
Source: Own elaboration.
Annex ii
Empirical
studies on the influence of fiscal decentralization on economic growth in
single-country studies
Author |
Space field |
Time field |
Dependent variable |
Variable of
fd |
Analytical framework |
Empiric methodology |
Main results |
Zhang and Zou (1998) |
28 provinces of China |
1980-1992 |
gypREG |
fd-Exp, fd-ExpEB, fd-ExpB+EB |
Model of endogenous growth of Barro
(1990) |
Fixed Effect Model. gls |
Fiscal decentralization has a negative and
significant impact on the economic growth |
Jin et al.
(2005) |
29 provinces of China |
1982-1992 |
gypREG |
fd-Exp, fd-ExpEB, fd-ExpB+EB |
Model of endogenous growth of Barro
(1990) |
Fixed Effect Model. gls |
Decentralization of expenditure promote the
economic growth |
Xie et al.
(1999) |
50 states of USA |
1948-1994 |
gypEST |
fd-Exp |
Model of endogenous growth of Barro
(1990) |
ols |
Existing spending shares for local and state
governments are consistent with the objective of maximizing economy’s growth |
Lin and Liu (2000) |
28 provinces of China |
1970-1993 |
gypREG |
mrr-Rev |
Model of neoclassical growth of Maniw et
al. (1992) |
Panel data. Fixed Effect Model |
The fiscal decentralization contributes
significantly to economic growth |
Zhang and Zou (2001) |
29 provinces of China |
1987-1993 |
gypREG CHINA |
fd-Exp |
Model of endogenous growth of Barro
(1990) |
Panel data. Fixed Effect Model |
Negative and significant association between
fiscal decentralization and economic growth |
16 major states of India |
1970-1994 |
gypREG INDIA |
fd-Exp, fd-Exppc, fd-Rev, fd-RevPC |
Panel data. Fixed Effect Model |
Fiscal decentralization is positively and
significantly associated with economic growth |
||
Behnisch et al. (2003) |
Germany |
1950-1990 |
tfpg |
cen-Exp, cen-ExpEP&SC |
They don’t make reference to any theoretical
pattern |
Time series analysis (further details are not
available) |
Negative and
significant association between expenditure decentralization and growth |
Akai and Sakata (2002) |
50 states USA |
1992-1996 |
gypEST |
fd-Exp, fd-Rev, aiI, aiII, pri |
Model of
endogenous growth of Barro (1990) |
Fixed Effects Model. ols |
The estimated
coefficient on fiscal decentralization is positive and statistically
significant |
Desai et al.
(2003) |
80 Russian regions |
1996-1999 |
gypt/gyp1990 |
rr-Taxrev |
They don’t
make reference to any theoretical pattern |
ols and tsls |
Tax retention
has a positive effect on the accumulative recovery output of regions |
Feld et al.
(2004) |
26 Swiss Cantons |
1980-1998 |
gypREG |
fd-Exp, fd-Rev, mat-Grants, Fisc-Comp, Fragm, Urban |
Model of neoclassical growth of Maniw et al. (1992) |
ols and tsls |
Matching
grants have a negative impact on economic performance while tax competition
is at least not harmful to economic performance |
Akai et al.
(2007) |
50 states of USA |
1992-1997 |
gypEST |
fd-Exp, fd-Rev |
Model of
endogenous growth of Barro (1990) |
Maximum likelihood estimation |
Hump-shaped
relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth |
Jin and Zou (2005) |
30 provinces of China |
1979-1993
1994-1999 |
gypREG |
fd-Exp, fd-Exppc, fd-Rev, fd-RevPC |
Model of
endogenous growth of Barro (1990) |
Panel data.
Fixed Effects Model |
Expenditure
and revenue decentralization levels should further diverge to benefit
provincial growth |
Carrion et al. (2006) |
17 Autonomous Communities |
1980-1998
1991-1996 |
gypREG |
fd-Exp y fd-Rev |
Model of endogenous
growth of Barro (1990) |
Panel data.
Fixed Effects Model. ols |
Process of
decentralization has had a positive effect on economic growth |
Source: Own elaboration.
References
Akai, Nobuo
and Masayo Sakata (2002), “Fiscal Decentralization Contributes to Economic
Growth: Evidence from State-Level Cross-Section Data for the United States”, Journal
of Urban Economics, 52, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 93-108.
Akai, Nobuo, Yukihiro Nishimura and Masayo Sakata (2007), “Complementarity, Fiscal Decentralization and Economic
Growth”, Economic of Governance, 8 (4), Springerlink,
New York, pp. 339-362.
Bahl, Roy
and Johannes Linn (1992), Urban Public Finance in Developing Countries,
Oxford University Press, New York.
Barro,
Robert (1990), “Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth”, Journal
of Political Economic, 98, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 108-125.
Baskaran,
Thushyanthan and Lars Feld
(2009), “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth in oecd Countries: Is There a
Relationship?”, cesifo
Working Paper Series, 2721, <SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1441152>,
May 2010.
Behnisch,
Alexej, Thiess Buettner and
Dan Stegarescu (2003), “Public Sector Centralization
and Productivity Growth: Reviewng the German
Experience”, zew
Discussion Paper, 02-03, Ludwig-Maximilians
University of Munich.
Bird, Richard
(1993), “Threading the fiscal Labyrinth: Some issues in Fiscal
Decentralization”, Nattional Tax Journal,
46 (2), National Tax Associaton, Washington, pp.
207-228.
Blair, Harry (1998), “Spreading Power to the Periphery: An Assessment of
Democratic Local Governance”, Program and Operations Assessment Report Nº 21,
usaid,
Washington.
Boadway,
Robin (1979), Public Sector Economics, Little, Brown and Company,
Boston.
Boadway, Robin (2001), “La necesidad de compartir los ingresos fiscales”, Revista Internacional de Ciencias Sociales, 167, unesco, Paris, pp. 103-110.
Bodman,
Phil and Kathryn Ford (2006), “Fiscal Decentralization and economic Growth in
the oecd”,
Macroeconomics Research Group, Discussion Papers 7, University of Queensland,
Brisbane St. Lucia.
Break, George
(1967), Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in the United States, The
Brookings Institution, Washington.
Brennan, Goffrey and James Buchanan (1980), The Power to Tax:
Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge.
Breuss,
Fritz and Markus Eller (2004), “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth: Is
There Really a Link?”, Journal for Institutional Comparisons, 2 (1), cesinfo-group,
Munich, pp. 3-9.
Carrion-i-Silvestre, Josep Lluis, Marta Espasa and Toni Mora (2006), “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth in Spain”, xiii Encuentro de Economía Pública, febrero, Barcelona.
Davoodi, Hamid and Heng-fu Zou (1998), “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth. A
Cross-Country Study”, Journal of Urban Economic, 43, Elsevier,
Amsterdam, pp. 244-257.
Desai, Raj, Lev Freinkman and Itzhak Goldberg (2003), “Fiscal Federalism and Regional
Growth, Evidence from the Russian Federation in the 1990s”, Policy Research
Working Paper 3138, World Bank, Washington.
Dethier,
Jean-Jacques (2000), Governance, decentralization, and Reform in China,
India and Russia, Kluwer Academic Press, London.
Eller Markus
(2004), “The Determinants of Fiscal Decentralization and its Impact on Economic
Growth”, Working Paper 2809, Viena University of
Economic-Business Administration, Viena.
Esteban, Sonia (2006), La descentralización fiscal y el crecimiento económico. Aplicación a las Comunidades Autónomas de Régimen Común (1997-2001), Proquest Information and Learning Español, Madrid.
Esteban, Sonia, Pablo de Frutos and María José Prieto (2006), “La descentralización fiscal y el crecimiento económico regional: aspectos normativos”, 10 Congreso de Economía de Castilla y León. Competitividad y marco institucional, Junta de Castilla y León, Valladolid, pp. 515-529.
Esteban, Sonia, Pablo de Frutos and María José Prieto (2008), “Fiscal decentralization and economic growth. Empirical evidence from a regional perspective”, Regional and Sectoral Economic Studies, 8 (1), La Coruña, pp. 1-25.
Feld,
Lars, Gebhard Kirchgässner
and Christoph Schaltegger
(2004), “Fiscal Federalism and Economic Performance: Evidence from Swiss
Cantons”, Marburg Working Paper on Economic, 20, Philipps-Universität
Marburg, Marburg.
Feld,
Lars and Jan Schnellenbach (2010), “Fiscal Federalism
and Long-Run Macroeconomic Performance: A Survey of Recent Research”, <SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1566390>, May 20, 2010.
Feld,
Lars, Thushyanthan Baskaran
and Jan Schnellenbach (2009), Fiscal Federalism,
Decentralization and Economic Growth: A Meta-Analysis, mimeo., University of
Heidelberg, Heidelberg.
Halder, Pragna (2007), “Measures of Fiscal Decentralization”,
Andrew Young Scholl of Policy Studies, Georgia State University.
Iimi,
Atsushi (2005), “Decentralization and economic growth revisited: an empirical
note”, Journal of Urban Economic, 57, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 449-461.
Jin, Hehui, Yingyi Quian
and Barry Weingast (2005), “Regional Decentralization
and Fiscal Incentives: Federalism, Chinese Style”, Journal of Public
Economics, 89 (9-10), Elsevier,
Amsterdam, pp. 1719-1742.
Jin, Jing and Heng-fu Zou (2005), “Fiscal
decentralization, revenue and expenditure assignments, and growth in China”, Journal
of Asian Economic, 16, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1047-1064.
King, David (1988), La economía de los gobiernos multinivel, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales, Madrid.
King, David (1995), “Public Policies in a Multinivel Government Model”, Papeles de trabajo, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales, Madrid.
Lin, Justin
and Zhiqiang Liu (2000), “Fiscal Decentralization and
Economic Growth in China”, Economic Development and Cultural Change,
49-1, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1-23.
Mankiw,
Gregory, David Romer and David Weil (1992), “A Contribution
to the Empirics of Economic Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economic, 107
(2), Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 407-437.
Martínez-Vázquez, Jorge and Robert McNab (1998), “Fiscal
Decentralization, Economic Growth, and Democratic Governance”, International
Studies Program Working Paper 9807, Georgia State University, Atlanta.
Martínez-Vázquez, Jorge and Robert McNab (2003), “Fiscal
Decentralization and Economic Growth”, World Development, 31, World Bank
Group, Washington, pp. 1597-1616.
Martínez-Vázquez, Jorge and Robert McNab (2006a), “Fiscal Decentralization, Macrostability and Growth”, Hacienda Pública Española, 179, Ministerio de Hacienda, Madrid, pp. 25-50.
Martínez-Vázquez, Jorge and Robert McNab (2006b), “Fiscal
Decentralization and Democratic governance”, in Paul Smoke, Eduardo J. Gómez and George F. Peterson (eds.), Decentralization in
Asia and Latin America: Towards a comparative Interdisciplinary perspective,
Edward Elgar Publishing, Massachusetts, pp. 15-41.
Oates, Wallace (1972), Fiscal Federalism, Harcourt Brace
Jovanovich, New York.
Oates, Wallace
(1993), “Fiscal decentralization and economic development”, National Tax
Journal, xlvi, National Tax
Association, Washington, pp. 237-243.
Oates, Wallace
(1995), “Comment on Conflicts and Dilemmas of Decentralization by Rudolf Hommes”, in M. Bruno and B. Pleskovic
(eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economic, The World
Bank, Washington, pp. 351-353.
Oates, Wallace
(1998), The Economics of Fiscal Federalism and Local Finances, Edward
Elgar, Aldershot.
Oates, Wallace
(1999), “An Essay on Fiscal Federalism”, Journal of Economic Literature,
37, American Economic Association, Pittsburgh, pp. 1120-1149.
Oates, Wallace
(2001), “Fiscal Competition and European Union: Contrasting perspectives”, Regional
Science and Urban Economic, 31, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 133-145.
Panizza, Ugo (1999), “On the Determinants of Fiscal
Decentralization: Theory and Evidence”, Journal of Public Economic, 74
(1), Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 97-139.
Pérez, Patricio and David Cantarero (2006), “Descentralización fiscal y crecimiento económico en las regiones españolas”, Papeles de Trabajo 5-06, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales, Madrid.
Phillips, Kerk and Gray Woller (1997),
“Fiscal Decentralization and ldc Economic Growth: An Empirical
Investigation”, Journal of Development Studies, 34 (4), Routledge, London,
pp. 139-148.
Porto, Alberto (2003), “La teoría del federalismo fiscal y las finanzas federales”, Documento de Federalismo Fiscal 4-2003, Universidad Nacional de La Plata, Buenos Aires.
Qiao, Baoyun, Jorge Martínez-Vázquez
and Yonsheng Xu (2008),
“The trade off between Growth and Equity in
Decentralization policy: China’s experience”, Journal of Development
Economic, 86, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 112-128.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (1994), Apuntes de crecimiento económico, Antoni Bosch, Barcelona.
Schnellenbach, Jan, Thushyanthan Baskaran
and Lars Feld (2009), “Creative Destruction and
Fiscal Intitutions: A Long-Run Case Study for Three
Regions”, Papers of Economic and Evolution, 0908, Max Planck Institute for
Economics, Leipzig.
Solé-Ollé, Albert and Alejandro Esteller-Moré (2006), “Decentralized Provision of Public Inputs, Government Responsiveness to Local Needs, and Regional Growth. Evidence from Spain”, xiii Encuentro de Economía Pública, febrero, Barcelona.
Solow, Robert
(1956), “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth”, Quarterly Journal
of Economic, 70, Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 65-94.
Thieben,
Ulrich (2000), “Fiscal Federalism in Western European and selected other
countries. Centralization or decentralization? What is better for economic
growth?”, Discusión Paper 224, Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, Berlin.
Thieben,
Ulrich (2003), “Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in high income oecd
countries”, Fiscal Studies, 24 (3), Institute for Fiscal Studies,
London, pp. 237-274.
Thieben,
Ulrich (2005), “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth in Rich oecd
Countries: Is there an Optimum?”, Economic Bulletin, 41 (5), Springerlink, New York,
pp. 175-182.
Thornton, Jhon (2007), “Fiscal decentralization and economic growth
reconsidered”, Journal of Urban Economic, 61, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp.
64-70.
Xie, Danyang, Heng-fu Zou and Hamid Davoodi
(1999), “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth in the United States”, Journal
of Urban Economics, 45, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 228-239.
Yilmaz, Serdar (2000), “The Impact of Fiscal Decentralization on
Macroeconomic Performance”, National Tax Association, Proceeding of the 92º
Annual Conference on Taxation, Atlanta, October, 24-26.
Zhang, Tao and
Heng Zou (1998), “Fiscal
decentralization, public spending and economic growth in China”, Journal of
Public Economic, 67, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 221-240.
Zhang, Tao and
Heng Zou (2001), “The
Growth impact of intersectorial and intergovernmental
allocation of public expenditure: Whit applications to China and India”, China
Economic Review, 12 (1), Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 58-81.
Recibido: 14 de abril de 2008.
Reenviado: 31 de julio de 2010.
Aceptado: 17 de agosto de 2010.
Sonia Esteban-Laleona. Es doctora en economía aplicada por la Universidad de Valladolid. Actualmente trabaja en el Departamento de Economía Aplicada de dicha Universidad, Campus Duques de Soria. Sus líneas de investigación actual son: federalismo fiscal y crecimiento económico. Entre sus últimas publicaciones destacan: La descentralización fiscal y el crecimiento económico. Aplicación a las Comunidades Autónomas de Régimen Común (1997-2001), Proquest Information and Learning, Madrid, (2006); en coautoría: “Status quo de la influencia de la descentralización fiscal sobre el crecimiento económico de las regiones”, xxxii Reunión de Estudios Regionales, Asociación Española de Ciencia Regional, Orense, pp. 1-22 (2006); en coautoría, “La descentralización fiscal y el crecimiento económico regional: aspectos normativos”, 10 Congreso de Economía de Castilla y León. Competitividad y marco institucional, Junta de Castilla y León, Valladolid, pp. 515-529 (2006); “Fiscal decentralization and econonomic growth. Empirical evidence from a regional perspective”, Regional and Sectorial Economic Studies, 8 (1), La Coruña, pp. 1-25 (2008).
Pablo de Frutos-Madrazo. Es doctor en economía aplicada por la Universidad de Valladolid. Actualmente trabaja en el Departamento de Economía Aplicada de dicha Universidad, Campus Duques de Soria. Sus líneas de investigación actual son: federalismo fiscal y crecimiento económico. Entre sus últimas publicaciones destacan: en coautoría: “Status quo de la influencia de la descentralización fiscal sobre el crecimiento económico de las regiones”, xxxii Reunión de Estudios Regionales, Asociación Española de Ciencia Regional, Orense, pp. 1-22 (2006); en coautoría, “La descentralización fiscal y el crecimiento económico regional: aspectos normativos”, 10 Congreso de Economía de Castilla y León. Competitividad y marco institucional, Junta de Castilla y León, Valladolid, pp. 515-529 (2006); en coautoría, “Fiscal decentralization and econonomic growth. Empirical evidence from a regional perspective”, Regional and Sectorial Economic Studies, 8 (1), La Coruña, pp. 1-25 (2008).
María Cristina de Miguel-Bilbao. Es doctora por la Universidad de Valladolid, en el Departamento de Economía Financiera y Contabilidad, en el Programa de Gestión y Administración de Empresas, 2005, de la Universidad de Valladolid, donde trabaja actualmente. Sus líneas de investigación actual son: sistema financiero, entidades de economía social. Entre sus últimas publicaciones destacan: “Efectos de las fusiones de cajas de ahorros de Castilla y León”, Revista de Contabilidad y Tributación, 326, Centro de Estudios Financieros, Madrid, pp. 187-202 (2010); en coautoría: “Gestión de la Obra Beneficio Social de las Cajas de Ahorro”, Revista de Estudios Cooperativos, 99, Escuela de Estudios Cooperativos, Madrid, pp. 60-84 (2009); “Cuentas anuales y plan de actuación para las fundaciones”, Revista de Contabilidad y Tributación, 321, Estudios Financieros, Madrid, pp. 181-208 (2009).
[1] See, for exemple, Blair
(1988), Martínez and Mcnab
(1998, 2006b) and Dethier (2000).
[2] Feld and Schnellenbach (2010) offer an excellent survey of the
current literature on fiscal federalism and long-run economic performance.
[3] In turn, Zhang and Zou
(2001) outline a greater complexity in the question of the sub-central
government expenditure, that increase the previous approach and develops a
model that links multiple sectors of public spending to multiple levels of
government and economic growth.
[4] Equally, Akai et al. referring to Barro (1990) developed a model, which considers differences
in the quality as well as complementarities of public services.
[5] As Iimi (2005)
indicates an interpretation of Davoodi and Zou (1998)’s model is that “When the productivity effect of
sub-national level government spending is relatively large compared with the
central government expenditure, fiscal decentralization has a positive effect
on the growth rate. However, holding the relative productivity constant between
governments, fiscal systems that are excessively decentralized are likely to
lower economic growth” (Iimi, 2005: 453). Therefore,
it is logical to expect that allocating budgetary resources to less productive
levels of government is harmful for the economic efficiency and therefore, for
the economic growth of a country. This implies that if the sub-national
governments are inefficient and faulty in the supply of local public goods, the
fiscal decentralization is not the best option.
[6] Jin et al. (2005) use the empirical
methodology of Zhang and Zou (1998) including a
variable dummy that grasps the effects of the national macroeconomic
fluctuations.